Viewpoint VIEWPOINT
One size does not fit all!
Dr Tim Lodge believes that framework agreements are stifling competition and creating a ‘one size fits all’ mentality that doesn’t actually fit anyone!
OVER the last thirty-five years or so, and like it or not, our society has wholeheartedly accepted that the market knows best in commercial matters. We are all buyers or sellers in that market, be it of goods, services or labour, and our right to buy and sell these things in a free and unfettered manner is a central principle of that doctrine.
As the owner and director of an SME, I have developed my business entirely within this context. Identifying the price to be asked for the product or service you provide in order to make the sale is half of what running a business is all about. The other half is trying constantly to improve the quality of the product or service so that it can compete more vigorously in the marketplace.
This philosophy, and the belief that we can create a better world by these means, is in fact enshrined in law, for example through the European Commission and the Office of Fair Trading; I’m not alone here.
So, I become particularly incensed when I see the rules, such as they are, being flouted. Which brings me to the main point of this article - framework agreements.
Framework agreements have become more and more common over the last decade or so, and their use is continually on the rise within the sports industry and elsewhere. The advantages they bring were summarised by Bob White, founder of US construction company, Mace, speaking in 2007.
(i) Clients can use them as significant drivers of change
(ii) They result in reduced competitive bidding/long-term relationships
(iii) Innovations and cost savings can be delivered through supply chain relationships
(iv) They will deliver continuous improvement agendas
(v) Long-term collaboration on capital programmes and long- term service revenues boost margins
(vi) They help to spread the overheads over a larger workload and produce fewer loss-making projects (less risk, less volatility)
(vii) They can improve performance-based reward
12 PC OCTOBER/NOVEMBER 2013 mechanisms
(viii) They encourage deeper relationships between
clients/contractors/supply chain demanding new upstream and downstream skills
There is a lot of business jargon here, but I feel the need to break this down a little.
(i) Clients can use them as significant drivers of change
Clients will do whatever it takes to achieve the best result for what they are led to believe is the right price, and this is true however the services are being provided. By its very nature, a framework agreement is inward and not outward looking so it is difficult to see where this change might come from. Innovations developed and available from outside of the framework will not become available to those within it.
(ii) They result in reduced competitive bidding/long- term relationships
But competition is good and it is the mechanism by which the market operates, achieving improved product quality at the lowest prices the market will sustain.
There’s nothing inherently good about a long term relationship, a relationship can be either good or bad, as many of us can no doubt testify from personal experience!
(iii) Innovations and cost savings can be delivered through supply chain relationships
I don’t see how the guarantee of work of a particular and pre- determined form can really stimulate innovation. Companies will provide only what it is agreed they should at the outset because, to do otherwise, would expose them to unnecessary risk. We have examples of precisely this phenomenon in our recent experience with both natural turf and artificial sports ground projects.
Privately funded projects are willing to accept innovative methods, whilst publicly funded projects, the sort that are regularly channelled through framework agreements, are not.
Similarly, when the market is made to apply at all levels in a chain, cost savings are more likely to be achieved. It is generally accepted that competition leads to price reductions, so the removal of
competition can only push prices up.
What I think is being referred to here are the actual costs of engaging in competition, for example those of undertaking appropriate procurement procedures. The independent private sector, engaged directly on the battlefield as it were, will happily absorb these costs as part of the business of doing what it does. It tends to be the public sector that has to cover expensive procurement costs, so this is an area where a framework serves only the client, the public sector or the
government; it does not serve the industry as a whole.
(iv) They will deliver continuous improvement agendas
Only from within the capacity of the framework providers and to an extent they are comfortable with. Any improving innovations developed outside of the framework will not be available. Also, with the assurance of work, where is the incentive to achieve improvements at all? Why not simply do what has been demonstrated to work in the past?
(v) Long-term collaboration on capital programmes and long-term service revenues boost margins
Large and long-term contracts have the potential to generate a good deal of profit. This is not news nor is it a phenomenon confined to framework agreements. Let’s not be naïve here, bigger margins mean greater costs to the client and, in the absence of competition, what contractor would ever want to reduce margins?
(vi) They help to spread the overheads over a larger workload and produce fewer loss-making projects (less risk, less volatility)
These are two quite different things. Overheads will be reduced within a framework for sure, but, as with procurement procedures, most individual companies would absorb this as part of their competitive approach. The advantages for the industry and for the client are, therefore, small. Indeed, the cost of procuring a framework agreement itself could very possibly approach the value of the potential savings within.
Projects that are without risk should definitely be exposed to
the full glare of free-market competition because, by definition, there will be many who could accomplish them, so the downward pressures on prices will be most severe.
(vii) They can improve performance-based reward mechanisms
Who are you Bob, my mother? Most of us want to do a good job and we all want to get properly paid for doing so. That’s the reason things happen, not because businesses want a pat on the head from government, thank you very much!
(viii) They encourage deeper relationships between clients/contractors/supply chain, demanding newupstream and downstream skills
Well, of course. But we’re back to this cosy and insular mentality from which externally developed ideas are excluded. If you follow this logic, you have to leave the free market behind entirely and nationalise everything.
The forming of relationships is a very basic human need; we do this in order to feel right about ourselves. But I don’t think this applies to companies or institutions. For myself, I like the free market environment. It’s cold occasionally, but invigorating, like a strong breeze. Governments in particular have an obligation to encourage and promote the whole of industry, not just the chosen ones from within it.
So let’s abandon this drift towards the dominance of the sports construction industry by framework agreements, and allow the heat of fair competition to forge new and better ways of serving our sportsmen and women.
Dr Tim Lodge, Agrostis Sports Surface Consulting.
www.agrostis.co.uk
Page 1 |
Page 2 |
Page 3 |
Page 4 |
Page 5 |
Page 6 |
Page 7 |
Page 8 |
Page 9 |
Page 10 |
Page 11 |
Page 12 |
Page 13 |
Page 14 |
Page 15 |
Page 16 |
Page 17 |
Page 18 |
Page 19 |
Page 20 |
Page 21 |
Page 22 |
Page 23 |
Page 24 |
Page 25 |
Page 26 |
Page 27 |
Page 28 |
Page 29 |
Page 30 |
Page 31 |
Page 32 |
Page 33 |
Page 34 |
Page 35 |
Page 36 |
Page 37 |
Page 38 |
Page 39 |
Page 40 |
Page 41 |
Page 42 |
Page 43 |
Page 44 |
Page 45 |
Page 46 |
Page 47 |
Page 48 |
Page 49 |
Page 50 |
Page 51 |
Page 52 |
Page 53 |
Page 54 |
Page 55 |
Page 56 |
Page 57 |
Page 58 |
Page 59 |
Page 60 |
Page 61 |
Page 62 |
Page 63 |
Page 64 |
Page 65 |
Page 66 |
Page 67 |
Page 68 |
Page 69 |
Page 70 |
Page 71 |
Page 72 |
Page 73 |
Page 74 |
Page 75 |
Page 76 |
Page 77 |
Page 78 |
Page 79 |
Page 80 |
Page 81 |
Page 82 |
Page 83 |
Page 84 |
Page 85 |
Page 86 |
Page 87 |
Page 88 |
Page 89 |
Page 90 |
Page 91 |
Page 92 |
Page 93 |
Page 94 |
Page 95 |
Page 96 |
Page 97 |
Page 98 |
Page 99 |
Page 100 |
Page 101 |
Page 102 |
Page 103 |
Page 104 |
Page 105 |
Page 106 |
Page 107 |
Page 108 |
Page 109 |
Page 110 |
Page 111 |
Page 112 |
Page 113 |
Page 114 |
Page 115 |
Page 116 |
Page 117 |
Page 118 |
Page 119 |
Page 120 |
Page 121 |
Page 122 |
Page 123 |
Page 124 |
Page 125 |
Page 126 |
Page 127 |
Page 128 |
Page 129 |
Page 130 |
Page 131 |
Page 132 |
Page 133 |
Page 134 |
Page 135 |
Page 136 |
Page 137 |
Page 138 |
Page 139 |
Page 140 |
Page 141 |
Page 142 |
Page 143 |
Page 144 |
Page 145 |
Page 146 |
Page 147 |
Page 148 |
Page 149 |
Page 150 |
Page 151 |
Page 152 |
Page 153 |
Page 154 |
Page 155 |
Page 156